Public education spending in Chile, 1880-1920: An uncredible commitment
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.22370/pe.2025.18.5024Keywords:
structural inequality, public spending, education, oligarchic society, institutions, ChileAbstract
This article analyzes the evolution of primary education expenditure in Chile during the period of the oligarchical parliamentarism (1880-1920), examining its relationship with structural inequality and its effects on economic development. Through a historical-comparative approach, the impact of land and power concentration on educational funding decisions is assessed, contrasting the Chilean experience with that of Japan and New Zealand. The results reveal that, while there was an increase in educational investment, it was limited by the interests of the ruling elite and their fear of social mobility, resulting in lower coverage compared to the other countries. The elimination of internal taxes and the recourse to external debt to finance public spending exacerbated this situation. It is concluded that structural inequality hindered a credible commitment to public primary education, perpetuating a legacy of inequity that still impacts the country's development. This study underscores the need for comprehensive educational policies that address both financial and structural aspects to promote greater equity and social mobility.
Downloads
References
ACEMOGLU, D. ROBINSON, J. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511510809
ACEMOGLU, D. JOHNSON, S., ROBINSON, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation, American Economic Review, 91 (5): 1369-1401. DOI: 10.1257/aer.91.5.1369
ACEMOGLU, D., ROBINSON, J. (2012). Why nations fail. The origin of power, prosperity and poverty. Estados Unidos: Crown Business. DOI:10.1355/ae29-2j
ALESINA, A., RODRIK, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth, The quarterly journal of economics, 109 (2): 465-490. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118470
ATKINSON, A. B. (1974). The economics of inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
BALAND, J., ROBINSON, J. (2008). Land and power: theory and evidence from Chile, American economic review 98 (5): 1737- 1765. DOI: 10.1257/aer.98.5.1737
BAUER, A. (1970). Expansión económica en una sociedad tradicional, Chile central en el siglo XIX, Historia, 9, 137-235.
BAUER (1975). Chilean rural society, from the spanish conquest to 1930. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
BECKER, G. (1975). Human capital. Nueva York: Columbia University Press.
BENABOU, R. (2000). Unequal societies: income distribution and the social contract, American economic review 90 (1): 96-129. DOI: 10.1257/aer.90.1.96
BENGOA, J. (1990). Historia social de la agricultura en chile, tomo 1: el poder y la subordinación. Santiago: Ediciones Sur.
BÉRTOLA, L., CASTELNOVO, C., RODRÍGUEZ, J., WILLEBALD, H. (2010). Between the colonial heritage and the first globalization boom: on income inequality in the southern cone, Revista de historia económica, 28 (2): 307-341.
BOIX, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: 97
Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/ CBO9780511804960
COLLIER, S. (1967). Ideas and politics of chilean Independence. Cambridge: The University Press.
DEININGER, K., SQUIRE, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: inequality and growth, Journal of development economics, 57 (2): 259-287. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304- 3878(98)00099-6
EASTERLY, W., LEVINE, R. (1997). Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions, Quarterly journal of economics, 112 (4): 1203-1250. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2951270
EASTERLY, W., RITZEN, J., Y WOOLCOCK, M. (2006). Social cohesion, institutions, and growth, Economics and politics, 18 (2): 103-120. https://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/redir. pf?u=https%3A%2F%2Fdoi.org%2F10.1111%2Fj.1468- 0343.2006.00165.x;h=repec:bla:ecopol:v:18:y:2006:i:2 :p:103-120
EASTERLY, W. (2007). Inequality does cause underdevelopment: insights from a new instrument, Journal of development economics, 84 (2): 755-776. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. jdeveco.2006.11.002
EDWARDS, A. (1936). La fronda aristocrática en Chile. Santiago: Ediciones Ercilla.
ENGERMAN, S. Y SOKOLOFF, K. (1994). Factor endowments, institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies: a view from economic historians of the united states, NBER Historical Paper 66.
ENGERMAN, S., SOKOLOFF, K. (2002). Factor endowment, inequality and paths of development among new world economies, NBER working paper 9259.
ENGERMAN Y SOKOLOFF (2005). Colonialism, inequality and long-run paths of development. NBER working paper 11057.
ENGERMAN, Y SOKOLOFF (2012). Economic development in the Americas since 1500. New York, Cambridge University Press.98
ERICKSON, L., VOLLRATH, D. (2004). Dimensions of land inequality and economic development, IMF working paper 04/158.
GARCIA-PENALOSA, C., CAROLI, E., AGHION, P. (1999). “Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories,” Journal of Economic Literature, 37 (4): 1615-1660. DOI: 10.1257/jel.37.4.1615
GALOR, O., MOAV, O. Y VOLLRATH, D. (2003). Land inequality and the origin of divergence and overtaking in the growth process: Theory and evidence, Working Paper, 2003- 04, Brown University, Department of Economics, Providence, RI.
GALOR, O., VOLLRATH, D. (2009). Inequality in land ownership, the emergence of human capital promoting institutions and the great divergence, Review of economic studies, 76 (1): 143-179. https://econpapers.repec. org/scripts/redir.pf?u=http%3A%2F%2Fhdl.handle. net%2F10.1111%2Fj.1467-937X.2008.00506.x;h=repec:ou p:restud:v:76:y:2009:i:1:p:143-179
GERBER, J. (1991). Public school expenditures in the plantation states, Explorations in economic history, 28 (3): 309-322. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-4983(91)90010-G
GLAESER, LAPORTA, LÓPEZ-DE-SILANES Y SHLEIFER (2004). ¿Do institutions cause growth? Journal of economic growth, 9 (3): 271-303. https://econpapers.repec.org/ scripts/redir.pf?u=http%3A%2F%2Fjournals.kluweronline. com%2Fissn%2F1381-4338%2Fcontents;h=repec:kap:jecgro :v:9:y:2004:i:3:p:271-303
GREZ, S. (1998). De la “regeneración del pueblo” a la huelga general. Génesis y evolución histórica del movimiento popular en chile (1810-1910). Santiago: Centro de Investigaciones Diego Barros Arana.
GOLDIN, C. (1999). Egalitarianism and the returns to education during the great transformation of american education, Journal of political economy, 107 (6): 65-94. DOI:10.1086/25010499
GREIF, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society, Journal of political economy, 102 (5): 912-950. http://dx.doi. org/10.1086/261959
HEYNEMAN, S. (2000). From the party/state to multi-ethnic democracy: education and social cohesion in europe and central Asia, Educational and policy analysis 22 (2): 173-191. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1164394
LINDERT, P. (2002). ¿What drives social spending? 1780 to 2020. En E. Kapstein y B. Milanovic (eds.), When markets fail, pp. 185-214. New York, Russell Sage Foundation.
MADDISON, A. (2023), Maddison project database 2023. https:// www.rug.nl/ggdc/historicaldevelopment/maddison/releases/ maddison-project-database-2020
MCBRIDE, G. (1936). Chile: land and society. Nueva York: Kennikat Press.
MITCHELL, B. (2007). International Historical Statistics, 1750- 2005. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
NORTH, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, Cambridge: Cambridge UP. https:// doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511808678
NORTH, SUMMERHILL Y WEINGAST (2000). Order, disorden and economic change: Latin America versus North America. En Bueno de Mesquita y H. Root (eds), Governinf for prosperity. New Heaven y Londres: Yale University Press.
NORTH, D., WALLIS, J. Y WEINGAST, B. (2009). Violence and social orders: a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511575839
PIKE, F. (1963). Aspects of class relations in chile, 1850-1960, Hispanic american historical review, 43 (1): 14-33.
RAJAN, R., ZINGALES, L. (2006). The persistence of underdevelopment: institutions, human capital or constituencies? CEPR Discussion Paper 5867.
RUBIO, YÁÑEZ, FOLCHI Y CARRERAS (2010). Energy as indicator of modernization in Latin America, 1890-1925, 100
Economic history review, 63 (3): 769-804. DOI:10.1111/ j.1468-0289.2009.00463.x
SAINT-PAUL, G., VERDIER, T. (1993). Education, democracy and growth, Journal of development economics, 42 (2): 399- 407. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(93)90027-K
SCHULTZ, T. (1964). The economic value of education, Nueva York: Columbia University Press.
Downloads
Published
How to Cite
Issue
Section
License
Those authors who have publications with this journal accept the following terms:
1.- Authors will retain their copyright and grant the journal the right of first publication of their work, which will simultaneously be subject to the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0 International) https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/deed.es which allows third parties to share, copy and redistribute the material in any medium or format.
- Attribution: credit must be given appropriately, provide a link to the license, and indicate if changes have been made. It may be done in any reasonable manner, but not in such a way as to suggest that the use is supported by the licensor.
- Non-Commercial: No use of the material may be made for commercial purposes.
- No Derivatives: Any remix, transformation or creation from the material, the modified material may not be distributed.
- No Additional Restrictions: No legal terms or technological measures may be applied that legally restrict others from making any use permitted by the license.
2.- Authors may adopt other non-exclusive license agreements for distribution of the published version of the work (e.g., depositing it in an institutional telematic archive or publishing it in a monographic volume) as long as the initial publication in this journal is indicated.
3.- Authors are allowed and encouraged to disseminate their work through the Internet (e.g., in institutional telematic archives or on their web page) before and during the submission process, which can produce interesting exchanges and increase citations of the published work. (See The Open Access Effect).